
When people think of banking today, they picture glass skyscrapers, Wall Street trading floors, or fintech apps to send money. Although it now feels like a complex modern invention, the reality of banking is far older and its origins surprisingly simple. Long before hedge funds or central banks, banking emerged to meet basic human needs: a safe place to store your wealth, a way to borrow when needed, and a system to trade with strangers using different currencies. These were practical solutions to everyday problems in ancient cities.
The first “bankers” were not investors or economists. They were temple priests in Mesopotamia guarding grain for farmers. They were moneychangers sitting at wooden tables in Greek markets, or Roman silversmiths weighing coins. And for centuries, money was not minted or printed, it was shells, metal bits, or scraps of paper promising future value.
What really led to the birth of banking?
The same forces that shape finance today were already being used. People needed to trust that their valuables were safe. Lenders took risks expecting rewards. Scarcity made certain goods precious. And incentives? They were the driving force behind it all. Historians still argue about where “real” banking began, or why. One thing is certain, once money appeared, banking soon followed. And the moment banks started lending, they were not simply moving money, they were creating new money. This is a cycle that still runs the world economy today.

Mesopotamia’s Sacred Bank Vaults
Banking began not with banks, but with storage. Around 2000 BCE in ancient Mesopotamia, there were no coins, no paper money, not even a standard currency. Trade ran on bartering and commodities such as grain or silver. No matter the form of wealth, the problem of safe storage of wealth was universal. The answer in Mesopotamia was simple, it was to trust the gods. Temples sat at the heart of every city, watched over by priests and guards, and seen as protected places. As a result, people brought their valuables (grains, metals, textiles) and left them in the temple for safekeeping. The priests carefully recorded everything stored.
Priests did not stop there. Those temple vaults were full of valuable goods often sitting unused or slowly spoiling. So why not lend some of it to local farmers or traders, who could repay it with interest after a harvest or sale? Before long, temples were not simply storage spaces, they were making loans and expecting returns [1].
If this system sounds familiar, it is because it reflects the basic model of modern banking. Trusted institutions hold deposits, lend them out, and earn returns on assets. The financial incentive is simple, assets in motion are more valuable than assets unused. Temples became the earliest versions of banks, not by design, by necessity.

Sumerians believed gods lived in the temple at the top of the ziggurats. Only priests and the elite could enter.
Rise of Greek Bankers
The invention of coins in the 7th or 6th century BCE should have made life easier. Suddenly, value could be stamped into metal, pocketed, and carried. But each Greek city-state minted its own coins, each with different weights, metals, and designs. Chaos ruled the marketplace. How could you trade when nobody agreed on what money was worth?
Enter the first professional bankers, the trapezites of Greece, named after the wooden tables or counters (trapeza) they worked from in the markets.
At first, these money changers were verifying the authenticity of foreign coins, weighing them, testing their purity, and making sure merchants were not getting scammed. Their role rapidly expanded and by the 4th century BCE, they were accepting deposits, making loans, and charging interest for the service. The fragmented Greek political world, with its dozens of competing currencies, made the trapezites indispensable. Without someone to verify, exchange, and hold coins, trade would have collapsed under its own confusion. They brought order and trust to an otherwise chaotic system, so much so that even today, the word for “bank” in modern Greek is trapeza or table.

Roman Empire Banking Networks
The Romans, who were never satisfied with doing things on a small scale, transformed banking into an imperial system. What started as simple money-changing in the markets of Greece evolved into a vast financial network stretching from Britain to Egypt. Rome needed a way to keep cash flowing across its massive empire without carrying piles of silver.
Bankers, known as argentarii or nummularii (from argentum, silver, and nummus, coin) appeared. These professionals offered a range of services including exchanging foreign currency, safeguarding deposits, and even transferring funds between accounts without coins physically changing hands. Roman-style wire transfers. Some operated privately, forming tight-knit guilds that dominated currency exchange and profited by charging commissions to traders and travelers. Others, known as mensarii, worked for the state. When a crisis struck (whether from famine or public disorder), these public bankers issued emergency loans to keep commerce flowing. It was an early version of what modern governments still do by using credit trying to stabilize the economy. At the time, interest rates floated up to 8 percent.
Much like modern financial systems, everything was based on trust. If Roman citizens or merchants lost faith in a banker’s word, the entire network could be paralyzed. While Rome never had stock markets or credit cards, it built the first real financial network. A surprisingly modern system designed to move money across an empire.

Lost Trust and Hidden Wealth
Regardless of the sophisticated Roman financial system, it never earned complete trust. When taxes rose, in times of war, or economic doubt, people hid their wealth. Archaeologists today still digging up these secret stashes of coins and other treasures buried away for centuries. No invading army or tax collector could get to it.
Why did people hide the “good” money? Because the “bad money” (debased, lightweight, or fake-looking coins) kept circulating, while the valuable coins were hidden. This is a well-known pattern called Gresham’s Law. Bad money pushes good money out of circulation. When people lose trust in the system, they keep what holds real value. The more valuable form of money will disappear from circulation as people hoard it, and the less valuable one will continue to be traded.
The same rule applies today, when investors lose trust, they usually rush to gold.
Benches, Shells, and the Origins of Banking Words
Even the words we use for banks today carry traces of their past. the Latin word mensa or the Italian banco both mean “table” or “bench.” Why? Because medieval money changers in the region worked from wooden benches in markets, exchanging local currencies. When a banker failed, his bench was broken (banca rotta or broken bench), the origin of our word “bankrupt.” Moreover, in Italy where banking thrived through the Renaissance and well into the 17th century, the terms “banker” and “exchanger” were often used interchangeably.
Before coins were minted, money came in other forms. In ancient China, cowrie shells were used as currency. These were so valuable that counterfeit versions were made from bone and bronze. The Chinese character for money still reflects the shape of these shells and Ghana’s currency, the cedi, takes its name from the word for cowrie. They were widely used as currency across Asia, Africa, and Oceania for millennia, remaining in circulation well into the 20th century. In fact, as late as the 1960s, it is said that Dutch explorers in New Guinea were forced to abandon their expedition after running out of cowries, as local carriers refused to accept any other form of payment.

Timeless Financial Incentives
Incentives, risk, and trust have governed banking since its origins in the temples of Mesopotamia and the marketplaces of Greece and Rome. The methods have evolved, with stone ledgers replaced by digital records and silver coins by central bank reserves, but the core dynamic remains.
Why did ancient priests start lending grain? For what purpose did Greek bankers carefully verify foreign coins? Why did Roman bankers invent account transfers? Because moving money creates opportunity, and managing risk earns reward. Even the fears persist. When crises hit, investors still hoard their safest assets, governments still intervene, and banks still struggle to maintain trust. Although modern finance may seem far more complex, at its core, this system follows the same ancient principles of trust, scarcity, risk and reward.
Related Posts
Reference
- Ferguson, Niall. The Ascent of Money: A Financial History of the World.
Penguin Press, 2008.